marble.jpg
 

American Fair Trade: Proprietary Capitalism, Corporatism, and the 'New Competition,' 1890–1940

American Fair Trade explores the contested political and legal meanings of the term fair trade from the late nineteenth century through the New Deal era. This history of American capitalism argues that business associations partnered with regulators to create codes of fair competition that reshaped both public and private regulatory power.

Rather than viewing the history of American capitalism as the unassailable ascent of large-scale corporations and free competition, American Fair Trade argues that trade associations of independent proprietors lobbied and litigated to reshape competition policy to their benefit. At the turn of the twentieth century, this widespread fair trade movement borrowed from progressive law and economics, demonstrating a persistent concern with market fairness - not only fair prices for consumers but also fair competition among businesses. Proponents of fair trade collaborated with regulators to create codes of fair competition and influenced the administrative state's public-private approach to market regulation.

New Deal partnerships in planning borrowed from those efforts to manage competitive markets, yet ultimately discredited the fair trade model by mandating economy-wide trade rules that sharply reduced competition. Laura Phillips Sawyer analyzes how these efforts to reconcile the American tradition of a well-regulated society with the legacy of Gilded Age of laissez-faire capitalism produced the modern American regulatory state.

 
 

REVIEWS

‘This is a fine work of legal history and business history, and it makes an important contribution to the literature on this formative period in the development of the American regulatory state.’
— Eric Hilt, Business History Review

'From Walton Hamilton and Milton Handler to Ellis Hawley and Herbert Hovenkamp, the very best legal and economic scholars have insisted upon the centrality of the law of unfair trade to the history of modern American capitalism. Laura Phillips Sawyer's American Fair Trade reanimates that entire tradition by demonstrating in superb and convincing detail the formative role of fair competition and trade associations in the development of the distinctive forms of public-private governance, administrative law, and economic regulation at the heart of both American capitalism and the modern American state.' William Novak, University of Michigan Law School


'What is fair trade? In this lucid, well-informed, carefully researched, and unfailingly judicious book, Laura Phillips Sawyer provides a boldly revisionist perspective on a historical perennial. In so doing, she joins the growing chorus of historians, lawmakers, businesspeople, and activists who are re-envisioning the antimonopoly tradition for the digital age.' Richard R. John, Columbia University


'American Fair Trade is destined to become a monument in the history of competition policy in the United States. Not only is Professor Sawyer an excellent writer, she is also a skilled integrator of political, economic, legal, and other historical ideas. No one has done a better job of identifying the political, social, and economic conflicts that gave rise to the fair trade movement, explain the resistance to it and the responses in the federal courts, and tell a coherent and believable story about why it finally collapsed. This is intellectual and business history at its very best.' Herbert Hovenkamp, University of Pennsylvania


'A timely and powerful history, this book joins a growing body of work to bring the anti-monopoly tradition out of the wilderness back to the center of American debate. By tracing the fair trade movement from its roots in nineteenth century antitrust into the modern trade association and feminist consumer movements, Laura Phillips Sawyer unearths vital resources to better reconcile equality, efficiency, and democracy in the twenty-first century.' Gerald Berk, author of Louis D. Brandeis and the Making of Regulated Competition


'The analysis is thorough, painstakingly footnoted, and strong on legal aspects. It breaks important ground and has few peers ... Recommended for graduate students through professionals.' M. Larudee, Choice


Business History Review | ERIC HILT

Eric Hilt is professor of economics at Wellesley College and a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). His recent publications include “The Berle and Means Corporation in Historical Perspective,” Seattle University Law Review (2019), and “Investment Banks as Corporate Monitors in the Early 20th Century,” American Economic Review (2017).

To the antimonopolists who supported the passage of the Sherman Anti- trust Act in 1890, the first two decades of federal antitrust enforcement were quite disappointing. Although the federal government won significant victories in suits against railroad cartels and major corporations such as Standard Oil, it also used the act to restrain labor unions and associations of small firms. The Supreme Court’s antitrust jurisprudence even seemed to favor large vertically integrated firms, in that it assessed whether the conduct of those enterprises violated the act by applying a test of reasonableness: the “rule of reason.” By contrast, a per se prohibition was applied to agreements among competitors, including trade associations of small manufacturers or retailers that sought to manage prices.Laura Phillips Sawyer’s American Fair Trade: Proprietary Capitalism, Corporatism, and the “New Competition,” 1890–1940 chronicles the evolution of the fair trade movement, which arose in reaction to this experience. An assistant professor at Harvard Business School, Sawyer shows how the founders of the fair trade movement responded to the growing influence of large corporations, and to the antitrust doc- trines that blocked the efforts of small firms to safeguard their interests, by seeking to reform American competition policy. Rejecting the Supreme Court’s insistence that only market forces should govern com- petition between firms, the fair trade movement sought to establish a regime of regulated competition in which markets would be partially managed by associations of small businesses acting in partnership with the government.

Much of the original impetus for this associational model of governance arose among specialty goods manufacturers, such as makers of watches or pharmaceuticals. In response to the proliferation of chain stores and other sources of competitive pressures in retailing, these firms utilized retail price maintenance contracts, which obligated retailers to adhere to a fixed price schedule in selling their products. Although the manufacturers argued that these contracts eliminated unfair trade practices and ensured that their products sold at a reasonable price, these contracts eliminated price competition between retailers, and in 1911 the Supreme Court held them to be in violation of the Sherman Act. One of the fair trade movement’s early goals was to reform antitrust law to make retail price maintenance contracts—which they rebranded as fair trade contracts—permissible. Through organizations such as the American Fair Trade League (AFTL) and the U.S. Chamber of Com- merce, the movement sought to extend the relatively permissive rule of reason to the legal evaluation of the conduct of trade associations and to establish government agencies that would work with those associations in the administration of competition policy.

Although some of the movement’s proposals, such as the Stevens Price Maintenance bill of 1914, were not enacted, the fair trade movement did have a lasting impact. The creation of the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) in 1914, which initially had the power to halt busi- nesses engaging in practices it determined to be unfair, was due in part to the movement’s efforts. And trade associations in a range of industries flourished, and made progress toward their goal of reshaping antitrust policy when the Supreme Court held that information sharing among association members—including some price information—did not violate the Sherman Act.

In the 1920s, trade associations received significant support from the Commerce Department and the FTC, which held conferences to promote the standardization and improvement of trade practices in particular industries. These developments were supported by Secretary of Commerce Herbert Hoover, who had little interest in antimonopoly concerns and instead sought to use partnerships between the federal government and industry associations to promote business efficiency and macroeconomic stabilization. The fair trade movement’s rhetoric and methods were in a sense co-opted by Hoover and repurposed toward a new set of goals that were much friendlier toward big business.

Sawyer argues that some of the corporatist elements of Hoover’s response to the Great Depression as president, and some elements of Roosevelt’s first New Deal, were another legacy of the changes promoted by the fair trade movement. In response to the economic cataclysm of 1930–33, business leaders used organizations such as the U.S. Chamber of Commerce to lobby for the kind of public-private cooperation for economic stabilization that Hoover had pursued in the 1920s, but on a much wider scale. Prominent executives argued for the outright cartelization of whole industries in order to eliminate price-cutting and overproduction, which they perceived to be the underlying cause of the Depression. Although Hoover was never willing to go that far, Roosevelt’s 1933 National Industrial Recovery Act (NIRA) reflected these influences. The National Recovery Administration relied on industry associations to devise codes of fair competition, which were justified as efforts to prohibit unfair practices such as sales below cost when in fact they sanctioned anticompetitive behavior and entrenched incumbent businesses. The Supreme Court struck down NIRA in 1935, and the book ends with a synopsis of the legacies of fair trade in the years after that decision.

One of the strengths of this book is that it carefully analyzes not only this evolution of antitrust law, but also the business practices developed by firms and trade associations that came into conflict with the law. This is a fine work of legal history and business history, and it makes an important contribution to the literature on this formative period in the development of the American regulatory state.

But the antitrust history in this book also makes it quite timely. In response to the perception that antitrust enforcement has been too lax in recent decades, some scholars have argued that the consumer welfare standard, which has been the dominant paradigm of antitrust authorities for the past forty years, should be abandoned. (See, for example, Marshall Steinbaum and Matt Walsh, The Effective Competition Standard: A New Standard for Antitrust [2018]; and Tim Wu, “After Consumer Welfare, Now What? The ‘Protection of Competition’ Standard in Practice” [Columbia Public Law Research Paper No. 14- 608, 2018].) Sawyer’s analysis makes it quite clear that the antimonopolists who supported the enactment of a federal antitrust statute, and the fair traders who sought to redeem the Sherman Act’s original promise, rejected the notion that antitrust should be focused exclusively on consumers. Instead, they sought to reshape American capitalism in a way that was fairer to small business and hoped to mitigate the pressures of market competition through cooperative action.

At the same time, this book provides clear examples of the perils of pursuing such an approach to antitrust. Efforts to restrain excessive competition or eliminate unfair pricing in practice sometimes became little more than a pretense for ratifying anticompetitive behavior. Some of the measures inspired by the fair trade movement in fact benefited big business at the expense of the small firms the movement sought to protect. An important lesson of that era is that measures motivated by antimonopoly concerns, if poorly designed, risk sanctioning monopoly.